For a couple of years I have been mulling over an idea to increase live donor donations. I have one mechanism that would only work in a very large setting - like in a large corporation.
Companies that pay for health coverage have an incentive to keep costs down. I forget the exact details (nor do I really care) but I think companies are required to keep ESRD (kidney failure) patients on their on health plans for a certain period of time until they can be transferred to Medicare (where ESRD is covered for people of any age.)
If these large companies can arrange healthy, willing employees to donate kidneys to other people in the company in need of a kidney, it would probably save them a lot of money, create tremendous good-will among employees, and probably make for great PR campaign, as well.
Again, large corporations' ESRD costs are astronomical so they have a large financial incentive to keep them in check - and what better way than making a sick employee healthy.
See this old post for this astronomical amount of money that could be saved by utilizing transplants instead of dialysis.
This blog deals with general healthcare policy and also with governmental policies which make it harder for people to get organ transplants which lead to decreased life expectancy. It also deals with implications of organ donation policies on life expectancy, quality of life, and economic issues. This blog is partially comprised of knowledge I gained while completing an MPH at NIU. This blog is dedicated to the memory of Harvey Schultz who suffered from Diabetes & ESRD.
Total Pageviews
Sunday, November 21, 2010
Thursday, November 18, 2010
The Scourge of our Kidney Transplant Waiting List
Today I was with a friend at the Jesse Brown VA Medical Center (and btw, if you covet socialized medicine, go there to see it personally and get mugged by reality -it will be enlightening.)
My friend had an appointment with the vascular surgery unit. By fate, I was sitting in one corner with 3 middle aged-older black males. Two are on the kidney transplant waiting list. One received a transplant 15 years ago. The two remaining gentlemen were discussing being on the waiting list and related things like how often they go for dialysis. I can see that both suffered from various co-morbidities and bodies are ravaged by effects if the ailment. I also know that the chance of older, sickly men receiving transplants in the urban Chicago area is not great at all. But they live with hope. Or, perhaps, ignorance is bliss. But I saw firsthand the terrible human toll of our dysfunctional organ donation system It is immoral!!!
My friend had an appointment with the vascular surgery unit. By fate, I was sitting in one corner with 3 middle aged-older black males. Two are on the kidney transplant waiting list. One received a transplant 15 years ago. The two remaining gentlemen were discussing being on the waiting list and related things like how often they go for dialysis. I can see that both suffered from various co-morbidities and bodies are ravaged by effects if the ailment. I also know that the chance of older, sickly men receiving transplants in the urban Chicago area is not great at all. But they live with hope. Or, perhaps, ignorance is bliss. But I saw firsthand the terrible human toll of our dysfunctional organ donation system It is immoral!!!
Thursday, November 11, 2010
How To Incent People Into Organ Donation: Possible Solution to Legal Conundrum
I've been thinking of a possibly legal way to encourage people to donate kidneys. Basically, people should be given the net present value of their donation around the time of their donation. This is to get around the legal problem of paying someone any "valuable consideration" for an organ donation. You are certainly legally allowed to pay for costs related to the organ donation process such as medical expenses, missed work, travel, etc.
I propose that paying everyone around the time of their kidney donation the lifetime expected value of medical costs relating to their kidney donation. For example, let's assume the costs related to the surgical removal of the kidney and related costs of missing work, etc. come to $20,000. Then let's say the person still has 30 years of life expectancy remaining. Also, assume that an annual CT scan, kidney function exam (creatinine level), and trip to specialists such as a urologist or nephrologist come to $2,000. Over the 30 years of the person's life that equals $60,000. Now add that to the $20,000 in costs for the time of the donation itself and you can give someone $80,000 and not really give them any "valuable consideration."
The economic underpinning of this plan is that people always discount the future. If I offer someone $1 today or $1 a year from now, it is rational for the person to take the money now because of reasons such as either of the people may be dead by then, the cost of uncertainty, and inflation.
Of course, purely altruistic donations are always welcomed, but we see that they cannot supply the levels of kidneys needed for the population.
I propose that paying everyone around the time of their kidney donation the lifetime expected value of medical costs relating to their kidney donation. For example, let's assume the costs related to the surgical removal of the kidney and related costs of missing work, etc. come to $20,000. Then let's say the person still has 30 years of life expectancy remaining. Also, assume that an annual CT scan, kidney function exam (creatinine level), and trip to specialists such as a urologist or nephrologist come to $2,000. Over the 30 years of the person's life that equals $60,000. Now add that to the $20,000 in costs for the time of the donation itself and you can give someone $80,000 and not really give them any "valuable consideration."
The economic underpinning of this plan is that people always discount the future. If I offer someone $1 today or $1 a year from now, it is rational for the person to take the money now because of reasons such as either of the people may be dead by then, the cost of uncertainty, and inflation.
Of course, purely altruistic donations are always welcomed, but we see that they cannot supply the levels of kidneys needed for the population.
Saturday, October 30, 2010
An old post: Government's Policy outlawing "valuable consideration" for organ transplants kills people every day
Saturday, August 14, 2010
All Rights Reserved to the Author
Policy Paper
PHHE 671
Eliyahu Lazovsky
December 1, 2009
Governmental Economic Policies to Increase Supply of Kidneys Available for Transplantation
The purpose of this proposed policy is to increase the numbers of kidneys available for transplantation. The methods will include government tax credits to live donors and the families or estates of deceased donors. Another method will be to align the incentives of current Medicare policies to focus on the current best standards for treatment of ESRD (end stage renal disease) and not merely the current model which focuses on treatment (dialysis treatment) and not on a cure (a kidney transplant.) “Kidney transplantation is the most successful and cost effective treatment for renal failure and should represent the gold standard, yet not all patients receiving dialysis are suitable for transplantation, and there is evidence that selection criteria vary widely” (Oniscu, 2003, p.1).
Currently many people die annually while awaiting a renal transplant, otherwise known as a kidney transplant. “As of June 2008, there were more than 75,000 people on the kidney transplant list in America. Sadly, about 12 of these patients die every day while awaiting a kidney” (Brochure, Alliance for paired donation, 2008, p. 2). Also, on average, people who receive ideal kidney organs for transplants live over 13 years longer compared to those on dialysis (Ojo, 2001, p. 592).
There is currently a government policy forbidding “valuable consideration” which is legalese for money to be exchanged between parties in order for one party to supply a kidney to the other party who is suffering from ESRD. This policy was introduced as an attempt to squelch the market for trafficking of human organs. While the intentions might arguably have been noble at the time the legislation was passed, with the benefit of hindsight, the unintended consequence of this legislation leads to additional thousands of people dying annually who are on the U.S. kidney transplantation waiting registry but succumb to the vagaries of ESRD before a kidney become available for transplantation.
A further complication in the supply of kidneys available for transplantation is that under a change to Medicare passed during the presidency of Richard Nixon, medical care associated with ESRD is covered for all Americans. In other words, we have nationalized health care in the U.S. for the treatment of ESRD. The federal government pays, for among other things, the costs associated with dialysis, which is the treatment given to people who are suffering for ESRD when their kidneys are no longer able to filter out the toxins from their blood streams and so this cleansing is done artificially by a blood dialyzer.
There is a quirk in the federal government’s coverage of ESRD which encourages people to remain on dialysis (a treatment) instead of pursuing a kidney transplant (a cure) because the federal government stops insuring people who formally had ESRD three years after the kidney transplant. This is due to a law passed by Congress in 1999 which made it illegal to pay for the immunosuppressant drugs for more than 3 years after transplantation. This creates an externality whereby people who cannot afford the very expensive anti-rejection medications which can cost up to around $1500 per month (and transplant recipients must take these medications for the remainder of their lives to lower the risk that the graft will be rejected.) opt to remain on dialysis instead of pursuing a transplant.
“Expenditures per patient year show parallel trends, with hemodialysis costs at $71,889 in 2006, compared to $53,327 and $24,951, respectively, for peritoneal dialysis and transplant” (Report, 2008, figures 11.8 and 11.9).
The government lowers the supply of kidneys available, thus distorting the market by lowering the supply of kidney available to the market. The government also reimburses much more money for dialysis than it does for kidney transplants, which are cheaper, and more importantly, cures the patient and improves the patient’s quality of life because they no longer need to be hooked up to a dialysis machine for hours at a time (Medicare spends $150,000 annually on dialysis patients versus $17,000 annually for post transplant patients) (Article, Kidney Transplantation, 2009).
I propose a two pronged approach to deal with the problem. First of all, I propose a $50,000 tax refund for anyone who makes a live or deceased kidney donation. This will cause a larger supply of kidneys to be available for transplantation. Also, since everyone gets the same amount of money from the government, this should work to crowd out the illegal black market for kidney organs.
I also propose a change in the Medicare reimbursement structure to encourage kidney transplants. This should increase the incentive to doctors to perform more transplants with the newly increased supply of kidneys available for transplantation. Also, the government will provide lifetime Medicare coverage to former ESRD patients who receive transplants who do not have their own medical coverage which covers anti-rejection medication to make sure people who could get a transplant but who cannot afford the anti-rejections medications do not opt against transplantation which is actually worse for their health and much more costly in the long run.
There are two very important aspects to these policies. One aspect is that kidney transplantation increases the life expectancy of the patient compared to a patient on dialysis. Additionally, this policy would probably save the government money in the long run because transplants are much cheaper than dialysis and they are a one time occurrence, not something that the government needs to keep paying for year after year like dialysis. Also, the patients for whom the government continues to pay anti-rejection medication, this is substantially cheaper than dialysis treatment.
Economically, the government will focus on subsidizing kidney transplants instead of focusing on subsidizing dialysis. This shift in subsidy strategy will increase the supply of kidneys to the market and the supply curve will shift outward and the new equilibrium point will result in the quantity of kidney transplants shifting out, thus increasing the number of transplants that will take place. This will also decrease the dead weight loss to the society that currently exists from more money being spent on dialysis than the market would demand if not for the government guaranteeing payment for all patients with ESRD. This money can be spent on much better things – like on the kidney transplants themselves.
All Rights Reserved to the Author
Policy Paper
PHHE 671
Eliyahu Lazovsky
December 1, 2009
Governmental Economic Policies to Increase Supply of Kidneys Available for Transplantation
The purpose of this proposed policy is to increase the numbers of kidneys available for transplantation. The methods will include government tax credits to live donors and the families or estates of deceased donors. Another method will be to align the incentives of current Medicare policies to focus on the current best standards for treatment of ESRD (end stage renal disease) and not merely the current model which focuses on treatment (dialysis treatment) and not on a cure (a kidney transplant.) “Kidney transplantation is the most successful and cost effective treatment for renal failure and should represent the gold standard, yet not all patients receiving dialysis are suitable for transplantation, and there is evidence that selection criteria vary widely” (Oniscu, 2003, p.1).
Currently many people die annually while awaiting a renal transplant, otherwise known as a kidney transplant. “As of June 2008, there were more than 75,000 people on the kidney transplant list in America. Sadly, about 12 of these patients die every day while awaiting a kidney” (Brochure, Alliance for paired donation, 2008, p. 2). Also, on average, people who receive ideal kidney organs for transplants live over 13 years longer compared to those on dialysis (Ojo, 2001, p. 592).
There is currently a government policy forbidding “valuable consideration” which is legalese for money to be exchanged between parties in order for one party to supply a kidney to the other party who is suffering from ESRD. This policy was introduced as an attempt to squelch the market for trafficking of human organs. While the intentions might arguably have been noble at the time the legislation was passed, with the benefit of hindsight, the unintended consequence of this legislation leads to additional thousands of people dying annually who are on the U.S. kidney transplantation waiting registry but succumb to the vagaries of ESRD before a kidney become available for transplantation.
A further complication in the supply of kidneys available for transplantation is that under a change to Medicare passed during the presidency of Richard Nixon, medical care associated with ESRD is covered for all Americans. In other words, we have nationalized health care in the U.S. for the treatment of ESRD. The federal government pays, for among other things, the costs associated with dialysis, which is the treatment given to people who are suffering for ESRD when their kidneys are no longer able to filter out the toxins from their blood streams and so this cleansing is done artificially by a blood dialyzer.
There is a quirk in the federal government’s coverage of ESRD which encourages people to remain on dialysis (a treatment) instead of pursuing a kidney transplant (a cure) because the federal government stops insuring people who formally had ESRD three years after the kidney transplant. This is due to a law passed by Congress in 1999 which made it illegal to pay for the immunosuppressant drugs for more than 3 years after transplantation. This creates an externality whereby people who cannot afford the very expensive anti-rejection medications which can cost up to around $1500 per month (and transplant recipients must take these medications for the remainder of their lives to lower the risk that the graft will be rejected.) opt to remain on dialysis instead of pursuing a transplant.
“Expenditures per patient year show parallel trends, with hemodialysis costs at $71,889 in 2006, compared to $53,327 and $24,951, respectively, for peritoneal dialysis and transplant” (Report, 2008, figures 11.8 and 11.9).
The government lowers the supply of kidneys available, thus distorting the market by lowering the supply of kidney available to the market. The government also reimburses much more money for dialysis than it does for kidney transplants, which are cheaper, and more importantly, cures the patient and improves the patient’s quality of life because they no longer need to be hooked up to a dialysis machine for hours at a time (Medicare spends $150,000 annually on dialysis patients versus $17,000 annually for post transplant patients) (Article, Kidney Transplantation, 2009).
I propose a two pronged approach to deal with the problem. First of all, I propose a $50,000 tax refund for anyone who makes a live or deceased kidney donation. This will cause a larger supply of kidneys to be available for transplantation. Also, since everyone gets the same amount of money from the government, this should work to crowd out the illegal black market for kidney organs.
I also propose a change in the Medicare reimbursement structure to encourage kidney transplants. This should increase the incentive to doctors to perform more transplants with the newly increased supply of kidneys available for transplantation. Also, the government will provide lifetime Medicare coverage to former ESRD patients who receive transplants who do not have their own medical coverage which covers anti-rejection medication to make sure people who could get a transplant but who cannot afford the anti-rejections medications do not opt against transplantation which is actually worse for their health and much more costly in the long run.
There are two very important aspects to these policies. One aspect is that kidney transplantation increases the life expectancy of the patient compared to a patient on dialysis. Additionally, this policy would probably save the government money in the long run because transplants are much cheaper than dialysis and they are a one time occurrence, not something that the government needs to keep paying for year after year like dialysis. Also, the patients for whom the government continues to pay anti-rejection medication, this is substantially cheaper than dialysis treatment.
Economically, the government will focus on subsidizing kidney transplants instead of focusing on subsidizing dialysis. This shift in subsidy strategy will increase the supply of kidneys to the market and the supply curve will shift outward and the new equilibrium point will result in the quantity of kidney transplants shifting out, thus increasing the number of transplants that will take place. This will also decrease the dead weight loss to the society that currently exists from more money being spent on dialysis than the market would demand if not for the government guaranteeing payment for all patients with ESRD. This money can be spent on much better things – like on the kidney transplants themselves.
Thursday, October 28, 2010
Dialysis: Different options to elongate life for those with kidney failure
Ok. You are suffering from kidney failure (ESRD). You can't get a transplant or you'll need to wait on the transplant waiting list for a while. To survive until then, you go on dialysis. There are different types of dialysis. You should see this stellar article in the WSJ to be aware of your options. Keep in mind that there are different life expectancies depending on your decision. Just because Medicare or your insurance reimburses for the typical hemodialysis (3 times a week), that does not mean that is the best option. It's your life - make the educated decision, not the one the medical establishment trys to herd you towards.
Thursday, October 7, 2010
The Case for Legalizing the Sale of Organs
Check out this interesting article offering differing justifications to allow valuable consideration (AKA money) to be exchanged for organs to increase the supply of organs available for transplantation. Kudos to John Hudson of The Atlantic Wire for this discussion.
Tuesday, October 5, 2010
Dilemna in Organ Donation
There was recently a TV show episode of Fox's hit show House (Season 7 Episode 2 titled "Selfish") which gives a fictional dramatization of the agony a family goes through grappling with a transplant issue of which child will live and which will die.
When more organs are made available (in the most ethical manners possible, of course) for transplantation (through increased live donor donation, biotechnological breakthroughs, or increased collection of organs from cadavers), the agonizing choice that might theoretical need to be made or the harrowing period of time a person and their family spend hoping for a transplant on the organ transplant waiting list can be decreased from their current levels.
Kudos to the producers/writers/actors for bringing this issue into the public sphere in a most glaring manner.
When more organs are made available (in the most ethical manners possible, of course) for transplantation (through increased live donor donation, biotechnological breakthroughs, or increased collection of organs from cadavers), the agonizing choice that might theoretical need to be made or the harrowing period of time a person and their family spend hoping for a transplant on the organ transplant waiting list can be decreased from their current levels.
Kudos to the producers/writers/actors for bringing this issue into the public sphere in a most glaring manner.
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)